Thursday, July 08, 2021

Planned economy or market economy - why is socialism good?

 

(The caption reads: The new uncooperative movement - lying flat)


Yuanhang Yihao

3/3/2021

(Translator’s preface: This post appeared on the Red China website www.redchina.cn.org a couple of months ago.  It argues the case for a socialist planned economy and refers to the widespread passivity of Chinese workers who “lie flat” to resist the system.  In a sense, that’s also my criticism of this article: the author “lies flat” on the question of socialism replacing capitalism, saying that the way out towards socialism is dependent on capitalism coming to an end. As Mao said, however, “if you don’t hit it, it won’t fall”. The author’s name is a pseudonym, meaning Voyage One.)

In the Red Community Forum, "Activate" and "Righteousness" discussed the comparison between planned and market economies and the specific problems that planned economies may encounter in the future. This is a meaningful discussion.

We are opposed to imagining the future society, but in the process of building a new Marxist-Leninist movement, it is necessary to sum up the lessons of the past socialist revolution and construction and, on the basis of an analysis of the existing contradictions of capitalism, to look at how the future socialist revolution can solve the contradictions that capitalism cannot solve, which is also part of the theoretical preparation needed for future revolutions. As Marx said, "The skill with which bees build their hives puts many architects on earth to shame. But where the lamest architect is superior to the most dexterous bee from the beginning is that he has built the hive in his own mind before he builds it." Of course, such buildings built first in the mind must still be tested in practice; the availability of materials and the soundness of the structure have to be worked out gradually during the building process.

Why did Marx and Engels believe that the future socialist (communist) economy should gradually eliminate the commodity economy and introduce a planned economy? On the one hand, this is because Marx and Engels believed that only on the basis of a planned economy could the system of public ownership of the means of production be truly established and consolidated, thus eliminating the system of exploitation of man by man and oppression of man by man. On the other hand, it is also because Marx and Engels believed that only with a planned economy could the anarchy of production under capitalist conditions be eradicated and the enormous economic waste be eliminated, thus opening the way for the enormous development of the material productive forces.

Marx and Engels argued that the contradiction between the productive forces and the relations of production under capitalist conditions inevitably leads to increasingly serious economic crises, thus seriously hampering the development of the modern productive forces. The causes of such economic crises are, in turn, twofold: firstly, under capitalist conditions, the working masses are increasingly exploited and their purchasing power of consumption fails to keep pace with the growth of the productive capacity of modern large-scale industry, thus leading to serious overproduction and, consequently, economic crises; secondly, under capitalist conditions, there is no unified plan and individual capitalists decide on their own subjective and one-sided perceptions. The lack of coordination between investment and production plans inevitably leads to serious overcapacity in some sectors and serious undercapacity in others, thus causing serious disproportionality and waste of resources. (The Marxian theory of a declining trend in the rate of profit leading to a crisis will not be discussed here for the time being.)

For Marx and Engels, both of these crises (under-consumption and disproportionality) are inevitably brought about by private ownership of the means of production and the anarchy of production. Only by implementing a unified plan for society as a whole, on the basis of a scientific survey and study of the material needs of the people, and then making reasonable arrangements according to the labour force and various means of production available in society, so that the production capacity of each industry and each product is roughly equivalent to the social needs of that industry and that product, can the enormous waste brought about by the capitalist market be eliminated, the economic crisis be eradicated and guarantee the rapid and smooth development of the material productive forces.

Pragmatically speaking, since the beginning of the twentieth century, both capitalist and socialist practices have developed considerably, and the advantages of a socialist planned economy over capitalism in practice in overcoming the crisis of under-consumption and the crisis of disproportionality are either non-existent or quite insignificant. As far as under-consumption crises are concerned, after the Second World War, due to the greatly increased intervention of capitalist countries in economic activity and the conscious implementation of Keynesian macroeconomic policies, serious economic crises caused purely by the lack of purchasing power of the working masses have become almost non-existent. As for the problem of proportional coordination between the various sectors of the national economy, the socialist planned economy has also shown no advantage in practice over capitalism, and localised overproduction or underproduction has occurred frequently and sometimes severely.

After the October Revolution in the Soviet Union, a debate erupted in bourgeois economics circles about the feasibility of a socialist planned economy. During the debate, bourgeois economists such as Hayek argued that the elimination of private ownership and the market made it impossible for socialist planning authorities to collect and process the vast amounts of information necessary for sound 'economic calculation', and therefore it would not be feasible. It should be noted here that some Marxists believe that with the development of modern computer technology, especially big data and cloud computing, the information problem posed by Hayek can be completely solved. This is a misconception. Hayek's information problem is more about the large amount of information that people experience first-hand, acquired in specific contexts and which cannot be expressed in statistics, similar to what we often call "practical knowledge". Moreover, the information on which the so-called big data and cloud computing under capitalist conditions are based comes from the personal information of consumers stolen by monopoly capitalists and the privacy of citizens collected by the bourgeois state. Such technological means are incompatible with the socialist and communist morality of the future. The socialist, communist society of the future should not be a society full of cameras.

Why, then, do bourgeois economists believe that the capitalist market is superior to socialist planning? There are two main points: firstly, they believe that under private ownership, everyone will work hard and innovate in order to get rich and famous; secondly, they believe that the market can guide consumers and enterprises to make rational economic decisions and achieve an efficient allocation of resources. Both of these points are actually problematic as well. On the first point, in a capitalist society, the vast majority of workers do not have the means of production, so their motivation to work and create is limited; even if a few workers have illusions at the beginning (such as new migrant workers in the cities), in time, or when the second generation grows up, they will be disillusioned and no longer dream of getting rich but instead "lie flat "[1].

As for the market guiding consumers and enterprises to make rational decisions, bourgeois economists and writers in the pay of the bourgeoisie, have often made the so-called "invisible hand" look like a miracle. In fact, bourgeois economics itself has never proved in the strictest sense that the "invisible hand" can actually achieve an efficient allocation of resources. Adam Smith was strictly speaking only proposing a hypothesis. Until the end of the nineteenth century, bourgeois economists had not really proved mathematically that a so-called 'general equilibrium' could exist (i.e. that there was a set of prices that would guarantee a balance between supply and demand in all markets at the same time). It was only in the mid-twentieth century that bourgeois economists could barely prove that, with the addition of a series of extremely unrealistic assumptions (e.g. that both consumers and "manufacturers" had perfect information), the so-called "Pareto optimum" could be achieved under conditions of so-called "perfect competition". This so-called "Pareto optimum" is another strange concept of bourgeois economics, which says that resources are allocated in such a way that no one can improve his or her own welfare without harming others. In bourgeois economics, according to their own theory, it is impossible to measure and compare the total welfare of society, so one can only compare the welfare of one person with his or her own welfare.

The key issue here is the role of market prices. We know that both Marxists and bourgeois economists recognise that in a capitalist economy, capitalists produce in the pursuit of profit and private gain, and consumers generally behave in consumption to satisfy their personal interests. How, then, can society progress when all people seek personal gain? Ultimately, the theories of bourgeois economics are designed to demonstrate that when the demand of many consumers and the supply of many capitalists are added together, the interaction results in a price that reasonably reflects the 'preferences' of consumers and the costs of various social resources. In this way, both capitalists and consumers, guided by prices, can make choices that are consistent with the progress of society as a whole in the pursuit of their own interests. All the arguments for a market economy are ultimately based on this argument.

However, modern bourgeois economists' own research has concluded that in the actual capitalist economy, prices are in the vast majority of cases "incorrect", that is, they do not correctly reflect the interests of society or the costs to society. For example, almost all prices of goods do not include the environmental costs of these goods, not to mention the huge social costs imposed on workers such as 996[2] and sudden death from overwork (in bourgeois economics, the case of "incorrect" market prices is called "market failure"; the Chinese bourgeoisie translate this as "market distortion", as if the market is still very flexible, but occasionally fails). Thus, there is a society made up of selfish, self-interested people, guided by "incorrect" prices, desperately seeking outcomes where private benefits outweigh private costs but real social costs outweigh real social benefits (what we now often call "involution "), which not only does not lead to social progress in the long run, but also carries the risk of great catastrophe.

It is true that the practice of socialist planned economy in the twentieth century has not managed to surpass capitalism in terms of socially average labour productivity, as Lenin had promised, nor in terms of long-term growth rates of labour productivity. However, in terms of long-term economic growth rates over half a century or more, socialist countries can achieve rough parity with capitalist countries at a similar level of development over the same period. Of course, the bourgeois ideologues and liberals will cite the supposedly faster development of West Germany than East Germany as an example, but Marxists can also cite China compared to India as a counter-example. In the case of a large sample of socialist countries at the same level of development as capitalist countries, the long-term economic growth rate is roughly comparable and should be considered equal.

The real superiority of socialism lies not in economic growth, but in full employment, iron rice bowls, free health care, free education, workers' sanatoriums; in short, jobs for all, food for all, and a life of human dignity for all, rather than "struggling" for the capitalists day and night like cattle and horses, and being insulted and scolded by the capitalists like serfs.

How did socialism fail in history, given its great superiority? For one thing, the bureaucracy stole the leadership of the socialist state and then went down the road of capitalist restoration in order to enrich itself and to pass on its power and wealth for generations to come. The bureaucratic clique not only wanted to follow the path of capitalist restoration themselves, but also used the propaganda machine at their disposal to deceive the people, using the "high consumption" of the so-called "developed countries" to paint a picture of a big pie and the so-called "million dollar household" typical of the early restoration period to stimulate certain backward ideas among the working masses. They then desperately advocated the so-called "iron rice bowl, nurturing lazy people" and the idea that "there is no way out without reform and opening up" (similar to Thatcher's "There Is No Alternative"), causing many inexperienced working people to lose confidence in socialism.

Apart from the betrayal of the bureaucracy, there is another important reason for the failure of the socialist state in history. That is, as long as the capitalist world system exists, socialist countries need to participate in the international capitalist division of labour, to do business with capitalism, and therefore to compete with the capitalist economy. To compete in the capitalist market, either by technology, or by resources, or only by fighting for cheap labour. As socialist countries have historically been established in economically backward or even extremely backward countries, it is impossible to compete with developed capitalist countries in terms of sophisticated technology. A situation like that of the oil-exporting countries of the Middle East, rich in resources and small in population, is one that is unattainable. Thus, socialist countries can only compete with capitalist countries for the cost of labour. However, precisely because workers in socialist countries live like human beings, this necessarily means that labour cannot be "cheap". So, in the long run, as long as the capitalist world system exists, the socialist economy will not be able to compete with the capitalist economy, not because socialism is inefficient, but because capitalism is too barbaric. To use an analogy, the whole capitalist world system is a giant inward reel machine, where the rules of internal competition are to out-compete each other for ruthlessness and rottenness. Socialist countries can neither exploit the colonies and semi-colonies, nor have excess profits abroad, nor can they 996, and as a result they can only temporarily withdraw from the stage of world history.

If socialism cannot compete with capitalism in the capitalist world system, then where is the way out for socialism? The way out for socialism lies at the point where capitalism comes to an end. The great involutionary machine that is capitalism, involute to the end, is bringing endless disaster to mankind. This manifests itself on the one hand in the near collapse of the world's ecosystems and the imminent destruction of the material basis on which human civilisation rests. On the other hand, it is also manifested in the fact that, as the Communist Manifesto puts it, the bourgeoisie "cannot even ensure that its slaves maintain the life of slaves". Under modern capitalism, the inability of workers to maintain "slave-like conditions of existence" is not reflected in the absolute low level of material consumption, but in the inability of workers to complete the normal intergenerational reproduction of labour in conditions of dignity and without excessive physical and emotional exertion. The result of Chinese capitalism forcing hundreds of millions of workers to work inhumanely under extremely long and intensive hours is the gradual collapse of intergenerational reproduction of labour; this collapse will in turn lead to the collapse of capitalist accumulation and order of domination.

What, then, should a future socialist planned economy look like? First of all, the surplus products of society (and the depreciation of fixed assets) should be pooled together on the basis of the public ownership of the means of production of the whole society, and the distribution and use of the surplus products of society should be decided according to a unified plan on the basis of democratic discussion and decision-making by the whole society. Unlike the socialist economy of the twentieth century, the principle of using surplus products in the planned socialist economy of the future is not to achieve the expanded reproduction of material goods, but to first limit the level of material consumption of society as a whole to below the level required by the principle of ecological sustainability, and then to use part of the surplus products to transform the national economy so that it is based on an ecologically sustainable material foundation.

With the elimination of the extravagance and waste of the capitalist class and the cessation of the vast majority of the expansion and reproduction that is harmful to the ecosystem and the arms race of the capitalist countries, the total scale of social material production could be immediately and significantly reduced. In China, the resulting reduction in the production of material goods could account for about half of the current scale of material production, and the actual effective working time of the vast majority of workers could thus be immediately halved, allowing all workers to truly enjoy the right to rest commensurate with normal physical and psychological needs of human beings. The material production that would remain would be sufficient to provide all workers with sufficient nutritious food, dignified housing conditions, free medical care, free education and the necessary support in the event of their loss of working conditions.

In the long run, with the gradual increase in labour productivity, the working hours of all workers can be gradually reduced. For example, if the average social productivity of labour increases by 1% per year, after 70 years the average social working day or working week can be reduced by half; if the working day or working week remains the same, it is also possible to adopt the approach of adding two holidays per year, and after 70 years, about half a year can be a holiday for all workers. In this way, the ideal proposed by Marx in The German Ideology could eventually be realised: "in communist society, where nobody has one exclusive sphere of activity but each can become accomplished in any branch he wishes, society regulates the general production and thus makes it possible for me to do one thing today and another tomorrow, to hunt in the morning, fish in the afternoon, rear cattle in the evening, criticise after dinner, just as I have a mind, without ever becoming hunter, fisherman, herdsman or critic" so that the “free development of each individual" is thus "the condition for the free development of all".

 



[1] “Lying flat” (“躺平” in Chinese) is a relatively new phenomenon whereby workers engage in passive defiance of demands to work hard, seek promotion and otherwise “get ahead”.  These doors are closed for the majority of the workers, so they simply opt out. Some Chinese netizens say that the essence of lying flat is the dismantling of the Party’s control over people’s lives. The phenomenon has become so widespread that the official Xinhua news agency recently cited the example of medical workers fighting the pandemic to declare “The new generation is not a generation that chooses to lie flat, but one that chooses to work hard!” It just goes to show that, as they say, you cannot believe anything until the authorities deny it.

[2] A practice that has spread throughout China, beginning with high-tech companies in Shenzhen, which requires that employees work from 9:00 am to 9:00 pm, 6 days per week; i.e. 72 hours per week. It is grossly exploitative and has led to workers suiciding, unable to bear the pressure of work.

No comments: